Fisheries Subsidies disciplines-Assymetrical Outcomes for Developing Countries

 Fisheries Subsidies disciplines -Implications of WTO Negotiations: Asymmetrical Outcomes for Developing Countries

 The 11th Ministerial Conference was held from the 10-13 December, 2017 in Bueno Aires, Argentina. In relation to fisheries, the WTO members decided to:

1.  “Build on the progress made since the 10th Ministerial Conference as reflected in documents TN/RL/W/274/Rev.2, RD/TN/RL/29/Rev.3, Members agree to continue to engage constructively in the fisheries subsidies negotiations, with a view to adopting, by the Ministerial Conference in 2019, an agreement on comprehensive and effective disciplines that prohibit certain forms of fisheries subsidies that contribute to overcapacity and overfishing, and eliminate subsidies that contribute to IUU-fishing recognizing that appropriate and effective special and differential treatment for developing country Members and least developed country Members should be an integral part of these negotiations.” And
2. “Members re-commit to implementation of existing notification obligations under Article 25.3 of the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures thus strengthening transparency with respect to fisheries subsidies.”

Subsequent to the Ministerial Conference, there had been several debates (some members blaming others for not achieving an outcome).  This blog piece will discuss the issues for developing countries and the Asymmetrical Outcomes.



Issue 1: Developing Countries decapitated to utilize its fisheries resources

The developed and developing countries including the least developed economies are at different levels of development and subsidisation. As highlighted in the previous sections, the developed countries such as the EU and the “friends of fish” are advocating for the elimination of fisheries subsidies that they had themselves provided in the past in order to boost their fisheries sector.




A situation prevails where the developed countries are now in a position to dominate the global fisheries market, after building their fishing capacity on the basis of generous subsidies from the government. . The elimination of fisheries subsidies will decapitate the developing countries from utilizing their own fisheries resources. Several strategies have been applied by the proponents such as linking the special and differential treatment to stringent management measures which are burdensome for small states to achieve. With the cost of implementation outweighing the benefits, it is obvious that the small states would never be able to utilize their own fisheries resources. Secondly, the standstill provision proposed by New Zealand, aims to undermine the policy space for developing countries to develop its fisheries sector. The developing and least developed countries rely on fisheries for food security and livelihood. Further, some coastal states aim to domesticate their fisheries industry. However, the elimination of subsidies will derail such aspirations. In addition, if developing countries are prohibited from providing subsidies for capacity enhancement, then they are unlikely to develop fishing fleets to exploit their own marine resources in future.

Issue 2:  Shift in Bargaining Power towards few Developed countries DWFN for fish access rights.

The fisheries sector constitutes a demand and supply equation for fisheries access rights. The developing countries including the coastal States and LDCs are the holders of fish resources. The coastal States with their maritime boundaries, own a major share of the fish resources extending up to their EEZ. Under UNCLOS, these coastal states have the right to manage and exploit the resources within their EEZ. In doing so, the coastal States also have rights over the fisheries resources within their EEZ and will determine its management measures as well. As discussed in the previous section, the coastal States cooperate at the national and sub-regional level with various institutions to manage their fisheries resources. For highly migratory and straddling stock such as tuna and cooperation in the high seas, the coastal States are members of RFMOs and negotiate management measures to sustainably manage the resource.


Consequently, the coastal States are the owners of the fish resource and thus the holders of fish access rights. Most of the developed countries such as EU and the “friends of fish” are owners of fishing vessels. In order for these countries to fish in the EEZ of other countries, they have to bid for access rights i.e. buy rights to fish from the coastal states. Currently, there are several distant water fishing nations that compete for access rights, including China,




Japan, Korea, Thailand, EU and others. As a result the small coastal States that are holders of fish resources, have the opportunity to sell the access fishing rights of its EEZ to the highest bidder i.e. whoever provides the best price for the fisheries resources will get the right to fish. The developing countries therefore have some bargaining power. The coastal States also ensure that while providing the fishing rights, the right holder also adheres to the conservation and management measures in place. Even when the highest bidder gets the resources, fishing happens in a sustainable manner.


With the elimination of fisheries subsidies, the developing countries that possess fishing vessels and provide specific subsidies may be compelled to exit the market over time due to the high operating costs. However, the developed countries that are vessel owners and have undertaken fisheries reforms (and have a commercial interest), will remain. There will be few demanders of fish access rights in the market i.e. the EU and the “friends of fish”. The coastal states and other developing countries would not be able to develop their fisheries sector, given the constraints of disciplining fishery subsidies.


As a result, the developed countries with large fishing fleets will dictate the price of the fishery access rights to the small coastal states and thus there will be a shift in the bargaining power for fish access rights in the hands of a few developed countries. The developed countries can then dictate the price of the access rights, i.e. purchase the rights to fish at a lower price; thereby, monopolizing the entire fisheries market.


Issue 3: Stifling the Future Development of Commercial Fisheries Sector

The global trend in the fisheries sector currently shows that the developing countries’ export of fish and fish products exceeds that of the developed countries. The developing countries include coastal States that are owners of large fish resources within their EEZs and also providers of specific subsidies. Furthermore, the small vulnerable coastal states also envisage development of their fisheries sector and some would want to venture into commercial fisheries. Given that these countries are already members of RFMOs and sub-regional arrangements, their resources will be utilised in a sustainable manner. However, the provision of subsidies will be integral to ensure the development of their fisheries sector. The imposition of disciplines, such as the elimination of fisheries subsidies and stringent conditions to provide the subsidies will affect the development aspiration of these countries.



This would stifle the future commercial fisheries sector development in the developing countries.

Issue 4:  Binding decisions of different RFMOs in relation to Management and imposing it multilaterally on members

At the global level, countries are committed to conserving and sustainably managing the fisheries resources. This is evident from the commitments and membership of countries to the UNCLOS, the UN Fish Stocks agreement and the participation of countries in the RFMOs, sub-regional fisheries management and at the national level. In order to ensure that fish resources are sustainably managed, the coastal states, the Distant Water Fishing Nations and Cooperating Non-Members negotiate conservation and management measures. There are several management measures negotiated as highlighted in Table 1 and 2 as examples in the WCPFC and the IOTC. These management measures are negotiated, taking into account the conservation of resources and also the socio-economic conditions that prevail within the region. As such, the element of disproportionate burden is crucial in the negotiations.

In the current fisheries negotiations at the WTO, members that are linking management to the fisheries disciplines are using the WTO as a forum to impose the management measures under a legally binding framework on all the members and in the context of the WTO these measures do not take into account the full extent of the disproportionate burden on developing countries, in particular the least developed countries. Secondly some of the management measures imposed in the RFMOs are for the high seas jurisdiction. However in the context of the WTO, some proponents have extended these to territorial waters and EEZ.

For example, on the issue of transhipment at sea, the WCPFC regulation 2009-06 states that the measures shall not apply to transhipment of highly migratory fish stocks where fish is taken and transhipped wholly in archipelagic or territorial seas. Transhipments in ports or in waters under the national jurisdiction of a member shall take place in accordance with appropriate national laws. Furthermore the IOTC Resolution 17/06 states that a program to monitor transhipment at sea applies only to a large scale tuna long line fishing vessel. In the WTO, transhipment issues are also covered in the fisheries text including extending it to small scale fishing activities.

Another illustration is that of the issue of enhanced transparency that proponents such as the EU, ACCPU and New Zealand have been advocating. The proponents are demanding

50



information such as catch data by species, the status of fish stock, the kinds of conservation and management measures applied and the fish capacity management plan.

The request for catch data by species is purely a management issue. The CMM 2009-10 of the WCPFC provides for the monitoring of landing of purse seine vessels at ports so as to ensure reliable catch data by the species. The CMM further states that such information will be collected from the canneries and shall be handled in the “non-public domain” i.e. kept confidential. Catch data is important to determine the commercial interest of the competitors as well. For the EU, ACCPU and New Zealand, the provision of such data in the public domain through WTO transparency mechanisms is a means for them to provide access to such data for their industries to have a competitive advantage. The IOTC Resolution 15/02 also provides the caveat for mandatory statistical reporting requirements for the IOTC contracting and non-contracting parties. The members are to provide data on total catch by species and gear (catch and effort data only) for surface fishers, long line fishers and coastal fishers.

The issue of flag of convenience in the proposal from Indonesia is also an issue from the IOTC RFMO. It is linked to management measures. The Resolution 99/02 provides that the CP and the CNP shall take every possible action consistent with their relevant laws and (i) urge their importers, transporters and other concerned business people to refrain from transacting in and transshipping tunas and tuna-like species caught by vessels carrying out FOC fishing activities; (ii) to inform their general public of FOC fishing activity by tuna long line vessels which diminish the effectiveness of IOTC CMM and urge them not to purchase fish harvested by such vessels; and (iii) to urge their fish manufacturers and other concerned business people to prevent their vessels and equipment/devices from being used for FOC long-line fishing operators.


The developed countries have been selective in imposing management measures from the RFMOs which (i) have been agreed through negotiations within the RFMOS by members states. It is obvious that given that these proponents may not have achieved the negotiated outcomes in the relevant RFMOs, such measures are sought to be introduced into the WTO forum and to exacerbate it further, if caution is not exercised will be imposed on all WTO members under a legal framework.



However the proponents EU, New Zealand, Iceland and others that have linked management aspects under different provisions and shadowed it with the explanation of development, have in effect ignored other fundamental aspect of the CMM that are development driven. A few examples of requirements under the CMMs that are missing from WTO negotiations are provided below:

·         IOTC Resolution 03/01 on the Limitation of Fishing Capacity of Contracting Parties and Cooperating non-Contracting Parties states that the parties which have more than 50 vessels on the 2003 IOTC record of vessel shall limit in 2004 and following years the number of fishing vessels larger than 24 meters in length. The limitation number shall commensurate with the corresponding overall tonnage expressed in Gross Registered tonnage and where vessels are replaced the over tonnage shall not be exceeded.

·         The WCPC resolution 2013-06 on the criteria for developing CMMs states that the CMMs must not result in transferring directly or indirectly a disproportionate burden of conservation action on small states. As such new proposals on CMMs have to be assessed against set criteria. In cases where transfer of disproportionate burden of conservation is present, this needs to be mitigated by phased or delayed implementation, exemption from specific obligations, proportional or rotational implementation and the establishment of compensatory funds.

·         The WCPFC resolution of 2013-07 on Special Requirements of Small Island Developing States provides for a list of areas for assistance that must be provided to developing countries for implementation. These include capacity development training, institutional support, technical training on data collection, scientific research, stock assessment, by catches mitigation, fisheries science and administration. The CMM further states that assistance should also be provided for monitoring control and surveillance, technology transfer, support for domestic fisheries sector including ensuring SIDS and territories to account for 50% of total catch and value of highly migratory fish stocks by encouraging investment and collaborative arrangement. It further states the actions should not constrain coastal processing and use of transshipment facilities and associated vessels of SIDS to undermine legitimate investment in SIDS. The CCMs shall take action to eliminate barriers to trade in fish and fisheries products and promote activities of domestic fisheries sector and fisheries related businesses in SIDS and territories.





From the above, the strategy of the developed countries is virtually clear in that in the WTO it aims to (i) selectively bind the conservation and management measures of the different RFMO, that are serves its own commercial interest and (ii) modify some of the RFMOs CMM decisions that were negotiated among members in the RFMO and further expand their own interest in the process to achieve the outcomes they prefers and (iii) ignore the full development aspect in relation to developing countries even in the development of management measures in the RFMOs i.e. the element of disproportionate burden and special requirements of developing countries as a special and differential element in the WTO.

Issue 5: Undermining Development Provisions (SDT) in the Fisheries Subsidies Negotiations


The special and differential treatment provisions are integral in the fisheries subsidies negotiations. The current proposals in the fisheries negotiations focus mainly on the transition period for the implementation of the subsidies reform by members. Some proposals have also adopted a format similar to that of the trade facilitation agreement on declaring the capacity constraints and assistance needed to implement the fisheries disciplines. However, it should be noted that fisheries subsidies disciplines differ from trade facilitation and thus the latter approach may not be feasible. According to WT/COMTD/W/196, there is a six- fold typology to the special and differential treatment. These include (i) provisions aimed at increasing trade opportunities to developing country members, (ii) provisions under which WTO members should safeguard the interests of developing country member, (iii) flexibility of commitments of action, (iv) the use of policy instruments (v) transitional time-period and (vi) technical assistance and provision in relation to LDC members.


The fisheries proposal has limited the scope of the special and differential treatment to only selected time periods for implementation with the exception of the ACP proposal that has listed additional types of assistance. Through the WTO process of fisheries negotiations which is a legally binding agreement, the developed countries further aim to reduce the special and differential aspect of fisheries and at the same time expand on other commitments. The principle of special and differential treatment is embedded in other internationally legally binding instruments in relation to fisheries such as the UNCLOS and UN Fish Stock Agreement. Other non-legally binding agreements also have the recognised special and differential treatment (known as Special Requirements of Developing Countries).



The UN Fish Stocks Agreement for instance recognizes (i) the vulnerability of developing states which are dependent on the exploitation of living marine resources, (ii) the need to avoid adverse impact and ensure access to fisheries by subsistent, small scale and artisanal fisheries and (iii) the need to ensure that such measures do not result in transferring directly or indirectly, a disproportionate burden of conservation action upon developing states.


The fisheries proposal from the developed countries are either overriding or reducing the scope of the special and differential treatment. In the EU proposal for example, the SDT is conditioned on the implementation of fisheries management measures. The Indonesian proposal also has a similar language. It completely ignores the special and differential treatment provisions that members are entitled to under international agreements and disregards the aspect of “disproportionate burden”. The WTO process is selective in relation to the six-fold approach and only stipulates transition period as an accepted SDT practice. The Indonesian proposal recognizes special and differential treatment but with stringent measures that the assistance has to be mutually agreed by developed and developing countries. This defeats the purpose of assistance and also undermines the special requirements of developing countries which the members are obliged to provide without reason or negotiation should there be issue of disproportionality in international fisheries agreement. As a result, the special and differential treatment is undermined.


Issue 6:  Strategy to shift market dominance of fisheries into the hands of few developed countries- tuna related products too

Globally the demand for fish and fish products is projected to grow in 2022. The global fishmeal & fish oil market is projected to reach a value of USD 14.28 billion by 2022. The market is driven by factors such as growing trend in fishmeal & fish oil trade and the increasing global demand for quality fish. Moreover, the demand for aquaculture is increasing in export markets, which influences the supply of improved fishmeal & fish oil for animal production. On the basis of industrial application, fishmeal & fish oil were most widely consumed in 2016 in the pharmaceuticals industry.

According to the FAO 2016 State of the World Fisheries report, the share of the world fish production that is used for human consumption has risen substantially from 67% in the 1960s up to 87%. About 146 million tonnes of the fish are used for human consumption. The reminder 21 million tonnes are used for non-food products of which 76% was used in 2014




for fishmeal and fish-oil. The rest were largely used for numerous purposes including raw material for direct feeding in aquaculture. As such the by-product of the fisheries is also becoming an important industry.

The report further states that fish and fishery products represent the most traded segment of the world food sector and 78% of seafood products are estimated to be part of the international trade competition. In terms of the market share of fisheries trade, the developing countries world fisheries trade rose from 37% in 1976 to 54% of total fishery export value by 2014. The trade in fish and fishery product is primarily driven by the demand from developed countries, which dominate the fisheries import covering a share of 73% of the world imports. In the developed countries there is high dependence on imports to meet the demand for domestic consumption of fish. (FAO State of World Fisheries, 2016, 58)

As a result, the removal of fish subsidies would constrain the developing countries from developing their fisheries sector due to the inability of the small-scale fisheries to expand into commercial fisheries. Secondly, those developing countries that may be in a position to export fisheries product and are still in the competitive fishing industry, may exit the market once fisheries subsidies are eliminated. The only remaining players in the global fisheries industry would be the developed countries that have large fishing fleet with high gross tonnage. These will primarily include the EU and the “friends of the fish” group of countries including New Zealand and Iceland that will dominate the fisheries market. As a result the fisheries resources would be in the hands of a few developed countries who would control the entire fisheries market. Those countries such as India that are major players in the pharmaceutical industry for generic medication will also be affected. The second effect will be that these industries will also control the global value chain. The likely outcome will be that the developed countries will become the producers and manufacturers of fish and fish related products as well as global exporters, holding a major share of the global fish market. In other words, a reversal of the current state of global fish exports, the developed countries becoming the dominating players.

Issue 7:  Replicating Box Shifting Effects of Agreement on Agriculture in Fisheries Subsidies Negotiations

The fisheries subsidies negotiations and the prohibition of subsidies is a replication of the strategy employed by the developed countries for agricultural subsidies. The issue of agricultural subsidy is an ongoing debate in the WTO. The developed countries provided high levels of agriculture support during the Uruguay round agreement in 1994. Even though restrictions were applied under the agreement, most of the developed countries have retained the high level of support through “box shifting” i.e. moving most of its limited subsidies into the “Green Box” of subsidies. Even though the Green Box entitlements are available to the developing countries, however, due to resource constraints (fiscal budgetary restraints), they are unable to fully utilise these.

As a result, the imbalances exist to date in agriculture. Most of the developing countries are providing specific subsidies whereas the developed countries such as the EU and the friends of fish have shifted their fisheries subsidies towards non-specific subsidies. Negotiations on fisheries subsidies risk meeting a similar fate, whereby the developed countries may enjoy greater policy space in comparison to the developing and least developed countries. Under the current subsidies negotiations members are targeting disciplines as per Article 1 of the ASCM which targets specific subsidies. Accordingly, the developing countries will be the ones making substantial commitment while the developed countries will gain greater policy space and a competitive edge.




Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Rules on Fisheries Subsidies Negotiations: Implications for small scale fisheries

Analysis of New Fisheries Subsidies Chairs Text

Fisheries Subsidies Negotiations: The Real Catch on Market Access