Fisheries Subsidies Negotiations: The Real Catch on Market Access
Discussion 2: Fisheries Subsidies disciplines as a Market Access Issue
The 11th Ministerial Conference was
held from the 10-13 December, 2017 in Bueno Aires, Argentina. In relation to
fisheries, the WTO members decided to:
1. “Build
on the progress made since the 10th Ministerial Conference as reflected in
documents TN/RL/W/274/Rev.2, RD/TN/RL/29/Rev.3, Members agree to continue to
engage constructively in the fisheries subsidies negotiations, with a view to
adopting, by the Ministerial Conference in 2019, an agreement on comprehensive
and effective disciplines that prohibit certain forms of fisheries subsidies
that contribute to overcapacity and overfishing, and eliminate subsidies that
contribute to IUU-fishing recognizing that appropriate and effective special
and differential treatment for developing country Members and least developed
country Members should be an integral part of these negotiations.” And
2. “Members re-commit to implementation of existing
notification obligations under Article 25.3 of the Agreement on Subsidies and
Countervailing Measures thus strengthening transparency with respect to
fisheries subsidies.”
Subsequent
to the Ministerial Conference, there had been several debates (some members blaming
others for not achieving an outcome). As such this excerpt aims to enlighten
members on the specific issues that has made the Negotiations on Fisheries
Subsidies resulting in such a decision. This article will discuss the linkage between Fisheries Subsidies Disciplines and
Market Access Issues.
Please see http://wtocentre.iift.ac.in/workingpaper.asp
The developed country members have shown a strong
concern on the depletion of the fisheries resources and thus are advocating
sustainability of the resources at the WTO. On the other hand, the membership
at the WTO shares the common view that sustainability of the fisheries
resources is critical to the food security and livelihood of the developing and
least developed countries. However, there are also concerns with respect to the
economic growth and development of the fisheries sector in relation to the
disciplines on fisheries subsidies. These concerns of the developing countries
are also enshrined in the existing fisheries instruments under the “special
requirements of developing countries”.
Grynberg 2003 further reveals the motives of the
developed countries in the fisheries subsidies negotiation. “In the case of the
fisheries, proponents are a mixed collection of countries with commercial
interest and those which believe that fisheries subsidies disciplines will
constitute an important step towards environmental sustainability. With the
friends of fish group, substantial and clearly demonstrable commercial interest
is at stake for Iceland and New Zealand. Both the nations have a highly
efficient and competitive fishing fleet but neither carry significant
bargaining power. Iceland fisheries constitutes 75% of export earnings and
hence the government simply cannot compete with other WTO members on subsidies
i.e., the Icelandic economy cannot subsidies. In the case of New Zealand, which
has pursued a policy of aggressive unilateral liberalization, there is no opposition
to such subsidies.
In other words New Zealand and Iceland will both benefit from the exit
of other players, which are currently subsidizing from the fisheries market.
The EU has reduced its subsidies over time and has achieved the required level
of fleet capacity. It is therefore advocating for an even stronger position in
relation to the elimination of subsidies, as it will also benefit from less
players in the fisheries market. The issue of sustainability is used as a
disguise for enhancing market access in the sector. If the EU and the other so
called friends of fish were genuinely interested in fish stock depletion,
fisheries would have been a component of the disciplines on Agreement on
Agriculture. However “during the Uruguay round, political opposition to the
inclusion of fisheries under the reduction on Agreement on Agriculture came
from the EU and countries called the “friends of fish”. (Grynberg, 2003,505).
The application of the disciplines on fisheries
subsidies is therefore an application of the LET fisheries policy that will
provide a competitive advantage and increase the market share of the developed
countries such as the EU, Iceland and New Zealand. If caution is not exercised
in the fisheries negotiations, the resultant disciplines would mirror the loss
of policy space of the developing countries and asymmetric outcomes as seen in
the context of the agriculture negotiations in the Uruguay Round.
The developed countries held high levels of
agricultural support during the Uruguay round agreement in 1994. Even though
ceilings on some type of subsidies were applied under the agreement, most of
the developed countries have retained the high level of support through “box
shifting” i.e. moving most of their subsidies into the “Green Box” under which
unlimited subsidies can be provided. Even though the Green Box entitlements are
available to the developing countries, however, due to resource constraints
(fiscal budgetary restraints), they are unable to utilize them fully. As a
result, imbalances exist in the context of agriculture to date.
Under the WTO negotiations, the existing proposals
on the table from the European Union, New Zealand, Pakistan and Iceland and
Latin America focus on disciplines on fisheries subsidies in relation to specific
subsidies as opposed to horizontal subsidies. This is a replication of the
agriculture subsidies negotiations. According to the OECD database on
subsidies, the EU member countries have progressively, over the years, moved
their specific subsidies into budgetary support. The EU provides approximately
3.4 billion of annual subsidies to the EU fisheries sector, nearly 1 billion of
which is from the EU budget in the form of structural aid. At the national
level aid is estimated at 975 million and this is in addition to the lost
revenue resulting from fuel tax exemptions. Few EU fleets are profitable with
no public support. (Reforming EU Subsidies, 2011, np). For small economies the
fisheries sector is unorganized and small, thus government support is required.
Developed countries have managed shift to non-specific fisheries subsidies from
specific subsidies. As a result, under the current disciplines on fisheries
negotiations, the developed countries will not be making any major substantial
commitments. On the other hand, the developing countries which still provide
specific subsidies would be “caught in the net” i.e. required to discipline
subsidies by 2020, which is a span of three years. For countries such as the
EU, it took more than 20 years to undertake their fisheries sector reforms.
At present there are several world marine producers
in the fisheries market. The major worlds marine catch
producers are China (17.7%), Indonesia (6.54%), Peru (6.28%), USA (5.6%), EU-28
(5.17%), India (4.92%), Russia (4.65%), Myanmar (4.05%), Japan (4%), Vietnam
(3%), Philippines (2.5%), Chile (2.45%), Norway (2.38%), Thailand (1.97%) and
the rest of the world (28.75%). The data clearly shows the market share in
fisheries from the top 14 countries. Out of these 9 economies are developing
countries. The major competing developed countries are USA, Japan and Norway.
Please see for tabulation of the Major World Marine Catch Producers: http://wtocentre.iift.ac.in/workingpaper.asp
The removal of subsidies will translate into some of the dominant
players exiting the fisheries market. As previously mentioned, given that the
EU and the “friends of the fish” have shifted most of their specific subsidies
to non-specific categories, the removal of specific subsidies by others will
benefit the developed countries. It will boost their competitive edge in the
global fisheries market.
The disciplines on fisheries subsidies will act as
a deterrent to the entry of vessel owners from developing countries, to access
the fisheries resources. For small developing coastal states the fisheries
activities include (i) revenue generation from access fees from distant water
fleets, and
(ii)
domestic and foreign fishers
operating for export in the EEZ and territorial sea to supply canneries,
loining facilities and domestic processing facility and (iii) artisanal fishers
within the territorial sea for domestic and export markets. Further, in the
fisheries sector many small vulnerable coastal states governments have been attempting to localise
the distant water fisheries as well as developing linkages between inshore
fishing in the territorial sea and other sectors of their economies, which
includes tourism. (Grynberg, 2003, 504).
As a result, the disciplines on fisheries subsidies
will impede the development of the fisheries sector for small coastal states
within the large EEZ. For low income poor resource fishers, the disciplines on
subsidies will increase their cost of operations. Most of the fishing vessels
for low income resource poor fishers are traditional and not motorized. These
low income resource poor fishers will further be marginalized due to
elimination of subsidies. It will prevent the small fishers from engaging in
economical fisheries activities for their livelihood and food security
purposes.
The Government would not be in a position to assist
the small commercial fisheries sector to fully utilize its own fisheries
resources - even though under the UNCLOS coastal States have the right to
manage and exploit the fisheries resources within their EEZ. Independent of the
disciplines on fisheries subsidies, coastal states apply management measures as
per the national legislation in their territorial waters and in co-operation
with sub-regional fisheries organizations in their EEZ.
Even in the event that small scale fishers are carved out from the
application on fisheries subsidies disciplines, the scale and magnitude of
small scale fisheries differ from that of a developed country. As a result, the
small scale fisheries of small coastal States will be marginalised and market
access of fisheries captured by developed countries will remain unaffected.
Consequently, the inability of the coastal States
to utilize their own fisheries resources will translate into a greater share of
the fish stock resources being available for the distant water fishing nations
(DWFN). The DWFNs who will remain efficient in the market will be the EU and
the countries composed of the “friends of fish”. This group of countries
(including EU, Iceland and New Zealand) have already shifted most of their
specific subsidies to non-specific category. Initially with other players in
the fish access market including the developing countries, there would be
competition to bid for the access rights. However, if subsidies are eliminated
and should most of the developing countries exit the fisheries market, these
few developed countries will remain as dominant players and will bid for fish
access rights. The developed countries will have greater bargaining power to
determine the price of the access rights.
In other words, the elimination of fisheries
subsidies will accord to the developed nations (EU and the Friends of Fish) a
greater share of the existing fish quota rights of fish. Given that the
elimination of fisheries subsidies will drive the developing countries out of
the market. On the demand side of fishing access rights, due to the reduction
of specific subsidies in forms of fuels, vessel modernization and other related
subsidies, the developing nations that were once competitors may be compelled
to move out of the market, and those that may aspire to enter the commercial
fishing sector may never be able to reach that level. This reduction in the
market demand for fish access rights would lead to a surplus supply of fish
access rights.
The ultimate result will be that a few distant water fishing nations
that have already developed their fishing vessels and have shifted most of
their specific subsidies to non-specific category for example the EU and New
Zealand, (prior to the negotiations on disciplines on fisheries subsidies) will
dominate the demand side of fishing access rights. Developed countries such as
the United States may also be affected by the fisheries disciplines due to
their inability to provide specific subsidies. The few developing distant water
fishing nations including the EU would therefore be pure profit maximisers and
gain economic rent would be created in their favour. The bargaining power of
small coastal States would decline and the few Distant Water Fishing Nations
would dictate the price at which the access rights would be purchased. This
would create a monopoly or oligopoly over access rights and lead to market
domination by developed countries.
Comments
Post a Comment